The Market System



I.    Specialization and Exchange

A.      Advantages of Specialization of Labor

Specialization of labor refers to different units of labor being used differently in the production process.  In other words, some types of labor might be used to produce only one particular type of good while others are used to produce a different good.  In fact, as labor becomes more specialized then a laborer might become so specialized as to produce only one part of one good.  This is the case when an autoworker is used in only doing one task, say installing the front driver's side door on cars on an assembly line.

Based on this definition, consider two types of societies:

1.       "John Wayne" Society - consists of only rugged individualists who consume only that which they themselves produce.

2.       "Henry Ford" Society - consists of individuals who are all specialized labor and produce only one good (or only a part of one good).

Now let us compare the advantages and disadvantages of both types of societies.

The "Henry Ford" society has as its main advantage that labor productivity increases.  In fact, Henry Ford put into action the principle observed centuries earlier by the economist Adam Smith, that specialization of labor often has the effect of increasing total output.  Henry Ford as an entrepreneur changed how automobiles were produced.  Previously cars were produced by single, or at most a few, artisans each working to manufacture their own individual car.  The cars were "works of art" that were so expensive that only the rich could afford them.  Instead of artisans, however, Ford pioneered a production process by which cars were produced on an assembly line.  Individual workers were given a single job to do and the assembly line moved the car along as the specialized workers added parts.  (The Henry Ford museum has a more complete description of the assembly line and how its specialization increased productivity.)

The "John Wayne" society has as its main advantage that individuals do not need to rely upon others for their sustenance.  Its main disadvantage is the decreased productivity and resultant lowered standard of living that such a society would offer to adherents.  On the other hand, the main disadvantage of a "Henry Ford" society would be the reliance by individuals upon their fellow men.  That is, given that individuals in this society will desire to consume other goods than the single good that they produce, some method of exchange between individuals is necessary.  In our modern, highly specialized world, these methods of exchange are often quite complicated including transportation of the goods that we consume over large distances.  The implication of this reliance upon others is that were society to break down, or even experience temporary problems in the system of exchange, people would find it difficult or impossible to live.  When events like war or natural disasters occur, starvation or, at the least, a much-reduced standard of living commonly follows.

Of course, the fact is that no known society of humans has ever lived in a society where individuals only consume their own production.  Even pre-historic human societies had family groups, which allowed some specialization of labor.  In recent U.S. history, the groups of individuals most likely to be considered "rugged individualists" nevertheless remained dependent upon others.  "Mountain men," for example, are often portrayed as such rugged individualists but the fact remains that they existed because of the market for beaver pelts in Europe and the Eastern U.S.  The beaver pelts were used during the heyday of the mountain man to make top hats for fashionable society.   Mountain men traded their harvest of beaver pelts for their yearly sustenance at trading forts and trapper rendezvous.  When silk replaced beaver as the fashionable top hat then mountain men lost their livelihoods and their numbers declined.

While true "rugged individualists" have likely never existed, it is important to note that some, like mountain men, relied less upon others than we do today in our modern society. 

Thus, human societies have invariably relied upon at least some specialization of labor implying that the advantages of such specialization outweighs the disadvantages.  

 


B.      Necessity of Exchange

Exchange refers to the process by which individuals trade the goods that they produce for the goods that they wish to consume. Given that human societies have chosen to have specialization of labor, for the reasons discussed above, along with that specialization must come some system of exchange.

 


C.      Systems of Exchange

There are a number of possible systems of exchange.  In fact, human societies have used different types of systems during the course of history.  A few of these possibilities are discussed below.

1.       Force

The simplest system of exchange is one where ownership of resources and outputs are determined by force.  That is, by the person or group with the most ability to enforce its ownership through such measures as fear, intimidation and violence.  This system, although often illegal, remains widely used in the world today both with individuals and small groups but also between nations.

2.       Tradition (feudal societies)

Societies that use tradition to determine the basic economic questions of what to produce, how and who will receive the goods once produced are also known as class societies.  In this case, just as with European feudal societies of the middle ages, what was produced and who received it was determined by the class in which one was born.  Some individuals received more goods but provided protection against the illegal use of violence, sometimes of their neighboring class peers.  Others had the benefits of such protection but at the cost of some of their production going to those providing the protection.  Some societies were especially rigid as to the class an individual belonged to while others had some flexibility built into the system.  In any event, birth or tradition was the overriding means by which exchange was effected in such a system.

3.       Planned Economies

During the 20th century some societies, usually communist countries, turned to central planning usually by a strong, central government to control exchange.  In such economies, the central body made extensive and detailed plans for the type of production that would occur, sometimes taking such plans out for a number of years.  The most extensive example of a planned economy was the Soviet Union, which came into being during the early part of the century and eventually fell in 1991.

4.       Market Forces

Market forces refer to a system that allows individuals to decide themselves what to produce and consume based upon their own preferences, abilities and resources.  As discussed below, a "market" refers to a place where exchange occurs in such a system.  This may, as markets did originally, refer to a geographic location where exchange occurs but has come more commonly, with increased communication technology, to refer to the process of exchange itself.  A system of market forces is sometimes referred to as a "free market economy."

5.       Mixed Economies

Mixed economies refer to some combination of the two previous types of systems: (1) planned economies and (2) market forces.  Americans tend to think of the U.S. system as one where individuals are free to make market decisions - a free market system.  However, even a brief investigation reveals that the free market is not always free in the U.S.  The government both forbids some market activities (e.g., some drug use, markets in living bodies, etc.) as well as regulating a large number  of other market activities (e.g., other types of drug use, interstate commerce, health care, etc.)  In other instances, the government itself provides a large number of goods and services (e.g., information - the government is the largest provider of information, education, roads, etc.)  In all of these examples, the government is acting as the central planning agency in a planned economy.

The same is true of the few remaining examples of planned economies, albeit in reverse.  The central government in China, for example, has moved more and more towards a market economy while still keeping a tight central control on other forms of expression.  It is fair to say, in fact, that most, if not all, economies in the world today are mixed economies.  The mixture of government intervention and free markets does vary from economy to economy but nonetheless exist. 

 


II.      Definition of Terms

A.      The Market

Markets are related to the exchange of goods, services, and resources between buyers and sellers.  The original markets were geographic locations where exchange occurred.  We continue to have geographic markets in our society today where buyers and sellers gather to exchange goods.  The most common example of geographic markets is shopping malls. 

However, as technology has increased other types of markets have arisen that are not always tied to a geographic location.  The essence of a market, then, is a mechanism that facilitates exchange but does not necessarily involve the geographic gathering of buyers and sellers in a traditional market.  Often, exchange carried out through the use of even relatively simple technology such as newspapers, telephones, faxes, etc.  The advent of the internet has increased the use of technology to make easier exchange with web sites both selling goods but also allowing people to post for sell labor (e.g., web sites like monster.com that allow one to auction one's own labor) and other goods (e.g., web sites like www.ebay.com that allows one to auction virtually any type of good.)

In addition to the above type of markets, it is common to refer to markets that are specific to a type of good, service, or resource.  These markets may be diffuse - as is shown when one notes that, for example, "the labor market is doing well this year."  On the other hand, these markets may be quite specific, noting a specific type of labor market, say the market for people with a new bachelor's in economics degree.  (For information about this particular labor market see the Missouri State economics department web site.)  Or they may refer to the selling of a specific commodity, such as soybeans on the Chicago Board of Trade.


B.      An Economy

Suppose you read in a newspaper that, for example, the U.S. economy grew at a 3.2 percent annual rate in the second quarter of 2000.  References to the economy are common in our society exactly because it represents a concept important to society generally and, often, each of us as individuals. 

Just as with markets, the Economy is also related to the exchange of goods, services, and resources.  However, in this case, the economy refers to an aggregated set of production and consumption activities.  In other words, an economy consists of the workings of a number, often a large number, of distinct markets for goods, services, and resources.

However, what makes a certain set of production and consumption activities an “economy” while another grouping is not?  For example, it is common to refer to the U.S. economy, as noted above, but not common to refer to the U.S. and Norwegian economy.  That is because the individual states comprising the U.S. share a common geographic location and a common legal system while the U.S. and Norway share neither.  Hence, an economy is most often defined as a set of production/consumption activities that share either or both common geographic locations and common legal systems.

Economies are most often national economies, such as the U.S. economy, which share both geographic location and a legal system.  However, regional economies within a given nation are also both commonly referred to and quite useful in application.  For example, the Southwest Missouri regional economy is considered to consist of twenty-four counties in the Southwest portion of Missouri.  (The Missouri State Bureau of Economic Research publishes data on this regional economy.)  Multinational economies have also begun to be developed, mostly through attempts to create a common legal system between geographically close countries.  One example of such a multinational economy is the European Union (EU), which was formally created on November 1, 1993.  (For a brief history of the European Union see the EU web site.)


III.    Actors in the Market

This section briefly discusses the three different types of actors in a typical system, such as the U.S.  In essence, there are three general types of actors, households, firms, and the government, each of whose roles is discussed in more detail below.

A.      Households

·   Consumers of Goods and Services

·   Owners of Resources

·   Assumed to act to maximize well-being or satisfaction

·   Assumed that no internal conflicts in decisions

Basically, this assumption means that even though households often have more than one member that those members can come to an agreement about which decisions maximize satisfaction.  In addition, they can be consistent in such decision-making.  Obviously, this is assumption may sometimes be violated but is made for simplification.

 


B.      Firms

·   Producers of Goods, Services, and Resources

·   Buyers of Resources

·   Assumed to act to maximize profit

·   Assumed that no internal conflicts in decisions

Similar to households, this assumption means that even though firms may have conflicting interests – multiple owners, workers, management – that those conflicting interests can come to an agreement about which decisions maximize profit.  In addition, they can be consistent in such decision-making. 

Such an assumption is even more problematic for firms than for households.  That is because firms are often much larger than households, with correspondingly larger potential for conflicts.  In point of fact, in very large firms the individuals who make decisions for the firms, the managers, are often either not the owners of the firm or only have limited ownership.  In this case, there is large potential for decisions that are not in the interest of the firm – decisions that do not maximize profit.  Economists have spent quite a bit of effort discussing such incentive problems in both firms and households.  However, for the purposes for this class we will make the simplifying assumption that such conflicts do not exist.


C.      The Government

·   Provides a legal environment, ensuring private property rights

This represents the crucial role of government in a market system.  Without the enforcement of private property rights exchange would be difficult if not impossible, as those with more power would work to steal property, leading to loss of production and a breakdown of the market system.

·   Intervenes in cases where Market failure occurs

Markets do not always work optimally.  One of the major topics during this semester will be the analysis of different types of market structures, including one of the major types of market failures, monopoly power.  The lack of competition that occurs during monopoly causes markets to “fail”, which in this case implies inefficiency.

Markets also fail in a number of other instances.  Externalities are another common market failure.  An externality is said to exist in a market when a third party external to the exchange, that is someone who is neither the buyer nor the seller of the product, is affected by the exchange.  Externalities also cause inefficiencies in the market.  

There exist two different types of externalities.  In a positive externality, the third party benefits from the exchange.  An example of this type of externality would be vaccinations for illnesses.  If you decide to become vaccinated for an illness, say measles, then it reduces my chance of becoming ill even though I have not been vaccinated myself.  In fact, if everyone were vaccinated but me then I would have no incentive to purchase the vaccination.  However, if enough people behave in this manner, as they have an incentive to do, then the number of vaccinations will fall and epidemics will result.  Thus, the inefficiency caused by a positive externality is one where too little of the good, in this case vaccinations, are produced by the market.

In a negative externality, the third party is damaged by the exchange.  The classic example of a negative externality is pollution.  Suppose that a steel company builds a plant next door and begins production of steel, but that it also produces air pollution as a byproduct, which damages nearby residents through respiratory diseases.  The increased level of respiratory diseases is legitimately one of the costs of the production of the good.   However, because these costs are born by third parties, they are not factored into the profitability of the firms.  As a result, the firm produces too much steel and also too much pollution.  Thus, the inefficiency caused by a negative externality is one of overproduction of the good in the market.

For both types of externalities, government intervention may be able to correct the market failure, either by stimulating production, in the case of a positive externality, or suppressing production, in the case of a negative externality.

·   Provides public goods

A public good is defined based upon two crucial characteristics.

·   Rivalry – a good is rivalrous if only one individual can consume it at a time and non-rivalrous if multiple individuals can consume the good simultaneously.  Oranges, for example, are an example of a rivalrous good while roads are an example of a non-rivalrous good.

·   Exclusion – a good is exclusive if it is relatively easy (costless) to exclude consumers who do not pay for a good from consuming the good and non-exclusive if exclusion of non-paying consumers is difficult or impossible.  Oranges are also an example of an exclusive good while computer software is an example of a non-exclusive good.

A public good is defined to exist when the good is both non-rivalrous and non-exclusive.  In these cases, private provision of the good is likely to be inefficiently low because private parties will be unable to reap the full profits from production of the good, both because multiple consumers can use the good simultaneously and because it is difficult to stop its use by non-paying consumers.  As a result, the government often provides public goods.  Examples of public goods include roads, police and fire protection, and national defense.

·   Makes Normative Decisions

A good deal of the workings of government has to do with making normative, or opinion-based, decisions.  Examples of normative decisions commonly made by governments include taxation and welfare policies, regulation of public health and safety, and provision of public goods.

·   Not assumed consistent in its decision making

Unlike households and similar to many firms, governments tend to be large entities.  As noted in our discussion of this issue for firms, larger organizations have more internal conflicts and, hence, less consistency in decision making.  Many governments, including the U.S. system of government, are typically designed in order to have internal conflicts, a system of checks and balances with different branches of government with independent powers that, as a result, are sometimes in opposition to each other.  Furthermore, the many governmental officials have their own incentives that may vary between officials and over time.  For example, the primary incentive for elected officials is generally their desire to be re-elected in the future.  Re-election concerns may cause different officials to behave differently given such factors as the varying nature of their constituency.  As a result of these problems, the government will not be assumed to be consistent in its decision making unlike firms and households.

 


D.      A Circular Flow Model of an Economy

The circular flow model is presented in order to place together the three actors in market and mixed systems together in a single model demonstrating their interactions.  Graph 1, below, illustrates these interactions.  The flow of payments, either for goods and services, for resources, or for taxes are highlighted in red.  The flow of goods and services, resources, and transfers are highlighted in blue. 

As discussed above, households are consumers of goods and services, which they buy in goods and services markets.  In order to obtain the necessary money for such purchases, households sell resources in factor markets.

Firms are producers of goods and services, which they sell in goods and services markets.  The firms use the payments from such transactions to buy the resources in factor markets necessary to produce the goods and services. 

The government’s roles in the market system include gathering taxes from both households and firms.  They use tax revenue both to buy resources and to give transfers of wealth, such as welfare payments, to both households and firms.  While it may not be common to think of the government transferring wealth to firms, such is a relatively common occurrence in our society.  This may be done through tax breaks for favored firms – given perhaps to induce a firm to locate to a particular locale.  Or it may be done through subsidies for other firms, such as subsidies often given by the U.S. government for the production of certain agricultural products.



The government also serves the role of producing some goods and services, such as the public goods discussed above.  In this role, they must purchase resources, providing payments for their purchases, in the factor markets.  The goods and services produced by the government may either be sold through the goods and services markets or provided free of charge directly to firms and households.  For example, a price is now charged for entry into U.S. national parks and monuments.  Many other governmental provided goods and services may also require payment and, hence, go through the goods and services markets.

However, the immediate consumers do not pay directly for many other governmentally produced goods and services.  For example, governments do not commonly charge prices for fire and police protection.  Another example would be the provision of information, which the government often produces and provides without charge.  Libraries often have depository rights for such information, which is then disseminated to the public without charge.  Such information has also begun to be produced through the internet (The Bureau of Labor Statistics is one site that provides information on such things as employment, unemployment and prices.)


Back to Dr. Olsen's Curriculum Page